Skip to main content

Income and Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand

Introduction:

Income and cross-price elasticities of demand are crucial concepts in microeconomics that measure the responsiveness of quantity demanded to changes in income and the prices of other goods, respectively. Understanding these elasticities helps businesses and policymakers predict how consumer behavior will change in response to economic shifts. These measures go beyond simple price elasticity, providing a more complete picture of consumer demand.

Key Points:

  • Income Elasticity of Demand (IED/YED): Measures how quantity demanded changes in response to a change in consumer income.
  • Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand (CPED/XED): Measures how quantity demanded of one good changes in response to a change in the price of another good.
  • IED helps classify goods as normal (positive IED) or inferior (negative IED). Normal goods are further classified as necessities (IED between 0 and 1) or luxuries (IED greater than 1).
  • CPED helps classify goods as substitutes (positive CPED) or complements (negative CPED).
  • The magnitude of both elasticities indicates the strength of the relationship.

Main Content:

1. Income Elasticity of Demand (IED or YED)

Definition

Income elasticity of demand measures the percentage change in quantity demanded of a good resulting from a percentage change in consumer income, ceteris paribus (holding all other factors constant).

Formula

IED = (% Change in Quantity Demanded) / (% Change in Income)

or

IED = [(Q2 - Q1) / ((Q2 + Q1)/2)] / [(I2 - I1) / ((I2 + I1)/2)]  (Arc Elasticity - preferred)

IED= [(ΔQ/Q) / (ΔI/I)]=(ΔQ/ΔI) x (I/Q)
Where:
Q1 = Initial quantity demanded
Q2 = New quantity demanded
I1 = Initial income
I2 = New income

Interpretation

  • IED > 0 (Positive): Normal Good. As income rises, quantity demanded rises.
    • 0 < IED < 1: Necessity. Quantity demanded rises less than proportionately with income. Example: basic food items, electricity.
    • IED > 1: Luxury Good. Quantity demanded rises more than proportionately with income. Example: high-end cars, designer clothing, international travel.
  • IED < 0 (Negative): Inferior Good. As income rises, quantity demanded falls. Example: instant noodles (as income rises, consumers switch to more expensive foods), generic brands.

Example

If a consumer's income increases by 10% and their quantity demanded of organic vegetables increases by 15%, the income elasticity of demand is 1.5 (15%/10%). This indicates that organic vegetables are a luxury good for this consumer. If their quantity of bus rides decreases by 5%, the income elasticity is -0.5, thus making but rides an inferior good.

2. Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand (CPED or XED)

Definition

Cross-price elasticity of demand measures the percentage change in the quantity demanded of one good (Good X) resulting from a percentage change in the price of another good (Good Y), ceteris paribus.

Formula

CPED = (% Change in Quantity Demanded of Good X) / (% Change in Price of Good Y)

or

CPED = [(Qx2 - Qx1) / ((Qx2 + Qx1)/2)] / [(Py2 - Py1) / ((Py2 + Py1)/2)] (Arc Method)
CPED =[(ΔQx/Qx) / (ΔPy/Py)]= (ΔQx/ΔPy) x (Py/Qx)
Where:
Qx1 = Initial quantity demanded of Good X
Qx2 = New quantity demanded of Good X
Py1 = Initial price of Good Y
Py2 = New price of Good Y

Interpretation

  • CPED > 0 (Positive): Substitutes. An increase in the price of Good Y leads to an increase in the quantity demanded of Good X. Consumers switch from Y to X. Example: Coke and Pepsi. If the price of Coke rises, the quantity demanded of Pepsi increases.
  • CPED < 0 (Negative): Complements. An increase in the price of Good Y leads to a decrease in the quantity demanded of Good X. The goods are used together. Example: printers and ink cartridges. If the price of printers rises, the quantity demanded of ink cartridges falls.
  • CPED = 0: Unrelated Goods. A change in the price of Good Y has no effect on the quantity demanded of Good X. Example: shoes and orange juice.

Example

If the price of coffee increases by 10% and the quantity demanded of tea increases by 5%, the cross-price elasticity of demand is 0.5 (5%/10%). This indicates that tea and coffee are substitutes. If the quantity of coffee makers decreased by 8%, the cross price elasticity would be -0.8, indicating that the two goods are complements.

Strength of Relationship (using absolute values for CPED)

  • Close to 0: Weak relationship.
  • Farther from 0: Stronger relationship. A CPED of 2 indicates a stronger substitute relationship than a CPED of 0.5.

Mermaid Diagram (Conceptual)

graph LR
    subgraph Income Elasticity
    A[Consumer Income] --> B(Quantity Demanded)
    B -- Positive IED --> C[Normal Good]
    C -- 0 < IED < 1 --> D[Necessity]
    C -- IED > 1 --> E[Luxury Good]
    B -- Negative IED --> F[Inferior Good]
    end

    subgraph Cross-Price Elasticity
    G[Price of Good Y] --> H(Quantity Demanded of Good X)
    H -- Positive CPED --> I[Substitutes]
    H -- Negative CPED --> J[Complements]
    H -- CPED = 0 --> K[Unrelated Goods]
    end

Conclusion:

Income and cross-price elasticities of demand are powerful tools for understanding consumer behavior. IED helps categorize goods based on how their demand changes with income, distinguishing between normal (necessities and luxuries) and inferior goods. CPED, on the other hand, reveals the relationship between two goods, identifying them as substitutes, complements, or unrelated. Businesses use these elasticities for pricing strategies, product positioning, and forecasting, while policymakers utilize them to analyze the impact of taxes, subsidies, and other economic policies. The magnitude of each elasticity indicates the strength of the corresponding relationship.